张律师欢迎您的访问。
制药培训师 优秀兼职培训师 双语教师培训 技术转移培训师 财务 Carrefour 陈与义虞美人 姜夔鹧鸪天 朱熹鹧鸪天 瘗鹤铭 宋朝十八帝诗说 宋朝历代皇帝年号一览表 Decision Making
How to avoid cognitive biases in decision making
The Big Idea: Before You Make That Big Decision...
by Daniel Kahneman, Dan Lovallo, and Olivier Sibony
Dangerous biases can creep into every strategic choice. Here’s how to find them—before they lead you astray.
Thanks to a slew of popular new books, many executives today realize how biases
can distort reasoning in business. Confirmation bias, for instance, leads people
to ignore evidence that contradicts their preconceived notions. Anchoring causes
them to weigh one piece of information too heavily in making decisions; loss
aversion makes them too cautious. In our experience, however, awareness of the
effects of biases has done little to improve the quality of business decisions
at either the individual or the organizational level.
Though there may now be far more talk of biases among managers, talk alone will
not eliminate them. But it is possible to take steps to counteract them. A
recent McKinsey study of more than 1,000 major business investments showed that
when organizations worked at reducing the effect of bias in their
decision-making processes, they achieved returns up to seven percentage points
higher. Reducing bias makes a difference. In this
article, we will describe a straightforward way to detect bias and minimize its
effects in the most common kind of decision that executives make: reviewing a
recommendation from someone else and determining whether to accept it, reject
it, or pass it on to the next level.
The Behavioral Economics of Decision Making
For most executives, these reviews seem simple enough. First, they need to
quickly grasp the relevant facts (getting them from people who know more about
the details than they do). Second, they need to figure out if the people making
the recommendation are intentionally clouding the facts in some way. And
finally, they need to apply their own experience, knowledge, and reasoning to
decide whether the recommendation is right.
However, this process is fraught at every stage with the potential for
distortions in judgment that result from cognitive biases. Executives can’t do
much about their own biases, as we shall see. But given the proper tools, they
can recognize and neutralize those of their teams. Over time, by using these
tools, they will build decision processes that reduce the effect of biases in
their organizations. And in doing so, they’ll help upgrade the quality of
decisions their organizations make.
The Challenge of Avoiding Bias
Let’s delve first into the question of why people are incapable of recognizing
their own biases.
According to cognitive scientists, there are two modes of thinking, intuitive
and reflective. (In recent decades a lot of psychological research has focused
on distinctions between them. Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein popularized it in
their book, Nudge.) In intuitive, or System One, thinking, impressions,
associations, feelings, intentions, and preparations for action flow
effortlessly. System One produces a constant representation of the world around
us and allows us to do things like walk, avoid obstacles, and contemplate
something else all at the same time. We’re usually in this mode when we brush
our teeth, banter with friends, or play tennis. We’re not consciously focusing
on how to do those things; we just do them.
In contrast reflective, or System Two, thinking is slow, effortful, and
deliberate. This mode is at work when we complete a tax form or learn to drive.
Both modes are continuously active, but System Two is typically just monitoring
things. It’s mobilized when the stakes are high, when we detect an obvious
error, or when rule-based reasoning is required. But most of the time, System
One determines our thoughts.
Our visual system and associative memory (both important aspects of System One)
are designed to produce a single coherent interpretation of what is going on
around us. That sense making is highly sensitive to context. Consider the word
“bank.” For most people, it would signify a financial institution.
But if the same readers encountered this word in Field & Stream, they would
probably understand it differently. Context is complicated: In addition to
visual cues, memories, and associations, it comprises goals, anxieties, and
other inputs. As System One makes sense of those inputs and develops a
narrative, it suppresses alternative stories.
Because System One is so good at making up contextual stories and we’re not
aware of its operations, it can lead us astray. The stories it creates are
generally accurate, but there are exceptions. Cognitive biases are one major,
well-documented example. An insidious feature of cognitive failures is that we
have no way of knowing that they’re happening: We almost never catch ourselves
in the act of making intuitive errors. Experience doesn’t help us recognize
them. (By contrast, if we tackle a difficult problem using System Two thinking
and fail to solve it, we’re uncomfortably aware of that fact.)
This inability to sense that we’ve made a mistake is the key to understanding
why we generally accept our intuitive, effortless thinking at face value. It
also explains why, even when we become aware of the existence of biases, we’re
not excited about eliminating them in ourselves. After all, it’s difficult for
us to fix errors we can’t see.
By extension, this also explains why the management experts writing about
cognitive biases have not provided much practical help. Their overarching theme
is “forewarned is forearmed.” But knowing you have biases is not enough to help
you overcome them. You may accept that you have biases, but you cannot eliminate
them in yourself.
There is reason for hope, however, when we move from the individual to the
collective, from the decision maker to the decision-making process, and from the
executive to the organization. As researchers have documented in the realm of
operational management, the fact that individuals are not aware of their own
biases does not mean that biases can’t be neutralized—or at least reduced—at the
organizational level.
This is true because most decisions are influenced by many people, and because
decision makers can turn their ability to spot biases in others’ thinking to
their own advantage. We may not be able to control our own intuition, but we can
apply rational thought to detect others’ faulty intuition and improve their
judgment. (In other words, we can use our System Two thinking to spot System One
errors in the recommendations given to us by others.)
This is precisely what executives are expected to do every time they review
recommendations and make a final call. Often they apply a crude, unsystematic
adjustment—such as adding a “safety margin” to a forecasted cost—to account for
a perceived bias. For the most part, however, decision makers focus on content
when they review and challenge recommendations. We propose adding a systematic
review of the recommendation process, one aimed at identifying the biases that
may have influenced the people putting forth proposals. The idea is to retrace
their steps to determine where intuitive thinking may have steered them
off-track.
In the following section, we’ll walk you through how to do a process review,
drawing on the actual experiences of three corporate executives—Bob, Lisa, and
Devesh (not their real names)—who were asked to consider very different kinds of
proposals:
A radical pricing change.
Bob is the vice president of sales in a business services company. Recently, his
senior regional VP and several colleagues recommended a total overhaul of the
company’s pricing structure. They argued that the company had lost a number of
bids to competitors, as well as some of its best salespeople, because of
unsustainable price levels. But making the wrong move could be very costly and
perhaps even trigger a price war.
A large capital outlay.
Lisa is the chief financial officer of a capital-intensive manufacturing
company. The VP of manufacturing in one of the corporation’s business units has
proposed a substantial investment in one manufacturing site. The request has all
the usual components—a revenue forecast, an analysis of return on investment
under various scenarios, and so on. But the investment would be a very large
one—in a business that has been losing money for some time.
A major acquisition.
Devesh is the CEO of a diversified industrial company. His business development
team has proposed purchasing a firm whose offerings would complement the product
line in one of the company’s core businesses. However, the potential deal comes
on the heels of several successful but expensive takeovers, and the company’s
financial structure is stretched.
Three Executives Facing Very Different Decisions
While we are intentionally describing this review from the perspective of the
individual decision makers, organizations can also take steps to embed some of
these practices in their broader decision-making processes. (For the best ways
to approach that, see the sidebar “Improving Decisions Throughout the
Organization.”)
Improving Decisions Throughout the Organization
Decision Quality Control: A Checklist
To help executives vet decisions, we have developed a tool, based on a
12-question checklist, that is intended to unearth defects in thinking—in other
words, the cognitive biases of the teams making recommendations. The questions
fall into three categories: questions the decision makers should ask themselves,
questions they should use to challenge the people proposing a course of action,
and questions aimed at evaluating the proposal. It’s important to note that,
because you can’t recognize your own biases, the individuals using this quality
screen should be completely independent from the teams making the
recommendations.
Questions that decision makers should ask themselves
Preliminary Questions: Ask yourself
1. Is there any reason to suspect motivated errors, or errors driven by the
self-interest of the recommending team?
Decision makers should never directly ask the people making the proposal this.
After all, it’s nearly impossible to do so without appearing to question their
diligence and even their integrity, and that conversation cannot end well.
The issue here is not just intentional deception. People do sometimes lie
deliberately, of course, but self-deception and rationalization are more common
problems. Research has shown that professionals who sincerely believe that their
decisions are “not for sale” (such as physicians) are still biased in the
direction of their own interests.
Bob, for instance, should recognize that lowering prices to respond to
competitive pressures will have a material impact on the commissions of his
sales team (especially if bonuses are based on revenues, not margins). Devesh
should wonder whether the team recommending the acquisition would expect to run
the acquired company and therefore might be influenced by “empire building”
motives.
Of course, a preference for a particular outcome is built into every
recommendation. Decision makers need to assess not whether there’s a risk of
motivated error but whether it is significant. A proposal from a set of
individuals who stand to gain more than usual from the outcome—either in
financial terms or, more frequently, in terms of organizational power,
reputation, or career options—needs especially careful quality control.
Reviewers also should watch out for pernicious sets of options that include only
one realistic alternative—the one that the recommending team prefers. In such
cases, decision makers will have to pay even more attention to the remaining
questions on this checklist, particularly those covering optimistic biases.
2. Have the people making the recommendation fallen in love with it?
All of us are subject to the affect heuristic: When evaluating something we
like, we tend to minimize its risks and costs and exaggerate its benefits; when
assessing something we dislike, we do the opposite. Executives often observe
this phenomenon in decisions with a strong emotional component, such as those
concerning employees, brands, or locations.
This question is also best left unspoken but is usually easy to answer. It is
likely that Devesh will easily sense whether the members of the deal team have
maintained a neutral perspective regarding the acquisition. If they have become
emotional about it, the remedy, again, is to examine with extra thoroughness all
the components of the recommendation and all the biases that may have affected
the people making it.
3. Were there dissenting opinions within the recommending team?
If so, were they explored adequately? In many corporate cultures, a team
presenting a recommendation to a higher echelon will claim to be unanimous. The
unanimity is sometimes genuine, but it could be sham unity imposed by the team’s
leader or a case of groupthink—the tendency of groups to minimize conflict by
converging on a decision because it appears to be gathering support. Groupthink
is especially likely if there is little diversity of background and viewpoint
within a team. Lisa, for instance, should worry if no one in the manufacturing
team that is proposing the large investment has voiced any concerns or
disagreement.
Regardless of its cause, an absence of dissent in a team addressing a complex
problem should sound an alarm. In the long run, a senior executive should strive
to create a climate where substantive disagreements are seen as a productive
part of the decision process (and resolved objectively), rather than as a sign
of conflict between individuals (and suppressed). In the short run, if faced
with a recommendation in which dissent clearly was stifled, a decision maker has
few options. Because asking another group of people to generate additional
options is often impractical, the best choice may be to discreetly solicit
dissenting views from members of the recommending team, perhaps through private
meetings. And the opinions of those who braved the pressure for conformity in
the decision-making process deserve special attention.
Questions that decision makers should ask the team making recommendations
Challenge Questions: Ask the recommenders
4. Could the diagnosis of the situation be overly influenced by salient
analogies?
Many recommendations refer to a past success story, which the decision maker is
encouraged to repeat by approving the proposal. The business development team
advocating the acquisition to Devesh took this approach, using the example of a
recent successful deal it had completed to bolster its case. The danger, of
course, is that the analogy may be less relevant to the current deal than it
appears. Furthermore, the use of just one or a few analogies almost always leads
to faulty inferences.
The decision maker who suspects that an analogy to an especially memorable event
has unduly influenced a team’s judgment (a type of cognitive flaw known as
saliency bias) will want the team to explore alternative diagnoses. This can be
done by asking for more analogies and a rigorous analysis of how comparable
examples really are. (For more details on the technique for doing this, called
reference class forecasting, see “Delusions of Success: How Optimism Undermines
Executives’ Decisions,” by Dan Lovallo and Daniel Kahneman, HBR July 2003.) More
informally, a decision maker can simply prompt the team to use a broader set of
comparisons. Devesh could ask for descriptions of five recent deals, other than
the recently acquired company, that were somewhat similar to the one being
considered.
5. Have credible alternatives been considered?
In a good decision process, other alternatives are fully evaluated in an
objective and fact-based way. Yet when trying to solve a problem, both
individuals and groups are prone to generating one plausible hypothesis and then
seeking only evidence that supports it.
A good practice is to insist that people submit at least one or two alternatives
to the main recommendation and explain their pros and cons. A decision maker
should ask: What alternatives did you consider? At what stage were they
discarded? Did you actively look for information that would disprove your main
hypothesis or only for the confirming evidence described in your final
recommendation?
Some proposals feature a perfunctory list of “risks and mitigating actions” or a
set of implausible alternatives that make the recommendation look appealing by
contrast. The challenge is to encourage a genuine admission of uncertainty and a
sincere recognition of multiple options.
In his review, Bob should encourage his sales colleagues to recognize the
unknowns surrounding their proposal. The team may eventually admit that
competitors’ reactions to an across-the-board price cut are unpredictable. It
should then be willing to evaluate other options, such as a targeted marketing
program aimed at the customer segments in which Bob’s company has a competitive
advantage.
6. If you had to make this decision again in a year, what information would you
want, and can you get more of it now?
One challenge executives face when reviewing a recommendation is the WYSIATI
assumption: What you see is all there is. Because our intuitive mind constructs
a coherent narrative based on the evidence we have, making up for holes in it,
we tend to overlook what is missing. Devesh, for instance, found the acquisition
proposal compelling until he realized he had not seen a legal due diligence on
the target company’s patent portfolio—perhaps not a major issue if the
acquisition were being made primarily to gain new customers but a critical
question when the goal was to extend the product line.
To force yourself to examine the adequacy of the data, Harvard Business School
professor Max Bazerman suggests asking the question above. In many cases, data
are unavailable. But in some cases, useful information will be uncovered.
Checklists that specify what information is relevant to a certain type of
decision are also helpful. Devesh, for his part, could tap his experience
reviewing acquisition proposals and develop lists of data that should be
collected for each different kind of deal his company does, such as acquiring
new technology or buying access to new customers.
7. Do you know where the numbers came from?
A focused examination of the key numbers underlying the proposal will help
decision makers see through any anchoring bias. Questions to ask include: Which
numbers in this plan are facts and which are estimates? Were these estimates
developed by adjusting from another number? Who put the first number on the
table?
Three different types of anchoring bias are common in business decisions. In the
classic case, initial estimates, which are often best guesses, are used, and
their accuracy is not challenged. The team making the proposal to Lisa, for
instance, used a guesstimate on an important cost component of the capital
investment project. More frequently, estimates are based on extrapolations from
history, as they were when Devesh’s team predicted the target company’s sales by
drawing a straight line. This, too, is a form of anchoring bias; one cannot
always assume trends will continue. Finally, some anchors are clearly
deliberate, such as when a buyer sets a low floor in a price negotiation. The
trap of anchors is that people always believe they can disregard them, but in
fact they cannot. Judges who are asked to roll a set of dice before making a
(fortunately simulated) sentencing decision will of course deny that the dice
influenced them, but analysis of their decisions shows that they did.
When a recommendation appears to be anchored by an initial reference and the
number in question has a material impact, the decision maker should require the
team behind the proposal to adjust its estimates after some reanchoring. If Lisa
discovers that the investment budget she was asked to approve was derived from
the costing of an earlier project, she can reanchor the team with a number she
arrives at in a completely different way, such as a linear model based on
investment projects carried out in other divisions, or competitive benchmarks.
The aim is neither to arrive directly at a different number nor to slavishly
“copy and paste” the practices of benchmarked competitors, but to force the team
to consider its assumptions in another light.
8. Can you see a halo effect?
This effect is at work when we see a story as simpler and more emotionally
coherent than it really is. As Phil Rosenzweig shows in the book The Halo
Effect, it causes us to attribute the successes and failures of firms to the
personalities of their leaders. It may have led Devesh’s team to link the
success of the acquisition target to its senior management and assume that its
recent outperformance would continue as long as those managers were still in
place.
Companies deemed “excellent” are frequently circled by halos. Once an expert
brands them in this way, people tend to assume that all their practices must be
exemplary. In making its case for its capital investment, Lisa’s team, for
instance, pointed to a similar project undertaken by a highly admired company in
another cyclical industry. According to the proposal, that company had “doubled
down” on a moderately successful manufacturing investment, which paid off when
the economy rebounded and the extra capacity was fully used.
Naturally, Lisa should ask whether the inference is justified. Does the team
making the recommendation have specific information regarding the other
company’s decision, or is the team making assumptions based on the company’s
overall reputation? If the investment was indeed a success, how much of that
success is attributable to chance events such as lucky timing? And is the
situation of the other company truly similar to the situation of Lisa’s company?
Such difficult questions are rarely asked, in part because it may seem off-base
to take apart an outside comparison that is made in passing. Yet if Lisa simply
tries to disregard the comparison, she will still be left with a vague, but hard
to dispel, positive impression of the recommendation. A good and relatively
simple practice is to first assess the relevance of the comparison (“What about
this case is comparable with ours?”) and then ask the people making it to
propose other examples from less successful companies (“What other companies in
our industry invested in a declining business, and how did it turn out for
them?”).
9. Are the people making the recommendation overly attached to past decisions?
Companies do not start from scratch every day. Their history, and what they
learn from it, matter. But history leads us astray when we evaluate options in
reference to a past starting point instead of the future. The most visible
consequence is the sunk-cost fallacy: When considering new investments, we
should disregard past expenditures that don’t affect future costs or revenues,
but we don’t. Note that Lisa’s team was evaluating a capacity improvement in a
product line that was struggling financially—partly because it was subscale, the
team argued. Lisa should ask the team to look at this investment the way an
incoming CEO might: If I personally hadn’t decided to build the plant in the
first place, would I invest in adding capacity?
Questions focused on evaluating the proposal
Evaluation Questions: Ask about the proposal
10. Is the base case overly optimistic?
Most recommendations contain forecasts, which are notoriously prone to excessive
optimism. One contributing factor is overconfidence, which could, say, lead
Devesh’s team to underestimate the challenge of integrating the acquired company
and capturing synergies. Groups with a successful track record are more prone to
this bias than others, so Devesh should be especially careful if the business
development team has been on a winning streak.
Another factor frequently at work here is the planning fallacy. The planning
fallacy arises from “inside view” thinking, which focuses exclusively on the
case at hand and ignores the history of similar projects. This is like trying to
divine the future of a company by considering only its plans and the obstacles
it anticipates. An “outside view” of forecasting, in contrast, is statistical in
nature and mainly uses the generalizable aspects of a broad set of problems to
make predictions. Lisa should keep this in mind when reviewing her team’s
proposal. When drawing up a timeline for the completion of the proposed plant,
did the team use a top-down (outside-view) comparison with similar projects, or
did it estimate the time required for each step and add it up—a bottom-up
(inside-view) approach that is likely to result in underestimates?
A third factor is the failure to anticipate how competitors will respond to a
decision. For instance, in proposing price cuts, Bob’s team did not account for
the predictable reaction of the company’s competitors: starting a price war.
All these biases are exacerbated in most organizations by the inevitable
interplay (and frequent confusion) between forecasts and estimates on the one
hand, and plans or targets on the other. Forecasts should be accurate, whereas
targets should be ambitious. The two sets of numbers should not be confused by
senior leadership.
Correcting for optimistic biases is difficult, and asking teams to revise their
estimates will not suffice. The decision maker must take the lead by adopting an
outside view, as opposed to the inside view of the people making proposals.
Several techniques help promote an outside view. Lisa could construct a list of
several similar investment projects and ask her team to look at how long those
projects took to complete, thus removing from the equation all inside
information on the project at hand. Sometimes, removing what appears to be
valuable information yields better estimates. In some situations decision makers
might also put themselves in the shoes of their competitors. The use of “war
games” is a powerful antidote to the lack of thinking about competitors’
reactions to proposed moves.
11. Is the worst case bad enough?
Many companies, when making important decisions, ask strategy teams to propose a
range of scenarios, or at least a best and a worst case. Unfortunately, the
worst case is rarely bad enough. A decision maker should ask: Where did the
worst case come from? How sensitive is it to our competitors’ responses? What
could happen that we have not thought of?
The acquisition proposal Devesh is reviewing hinges on the target’s sales
forecast, and like most sales forecasts in due diligence reports, it follows a
steep, straight, upward line. Devesh may ask his team to prepare a range of
scenarios reflecting the merger’s risks, but the team is likely to miss risks it
has not experienced yet.
A useful technique in such situations is the “premortem,” pioneered by
psychologist Gary Klein. Participants project themselves into the future,
imagine the worst has already happened, and make up a story about how it
happened. Devesh’s team could consider such scenarios as the departure of key
executives who do not fit into the acquiring company’s culture, technical
problems with the target’s key product lines, and insufficient resources for
integration. It would then be able to consider whether to mitigate those risks
or reassess the proposal.
12. Is the recommending team overly cautious?
On the flip side, excessive conservatism is a source of less visible but serious
chronic underperformance in organizations. Many executives complain that their
teams’ plans aren’t creative or ambitious enough.
This issue is hard to address for two reasons. First and most important, the
people making recommendations are subject to loss aversion: When they
contemplate risky decisions, their wish to avoid losses is stronger than their
desire for gains. No individual or team wants to be responsible for a failed
project. Second, the fact that very few companies make explicit choices about
what level of risk they will assume only exacerbates individual managers’ loss
aversion.
This helps explain why Lisa’s colleagues had ruled out a new technology
providing an alternative to the proposed investment: They deemed it too risky.
To get her team to explore this option, she could provide assurances or (perhaps
more credibly) explicitly share responsibility for the risk. When launching new
ventures, many companies tackle this problem by creating separate organizational
units with different objectives and budgets. But dealing with excessive
conservatism in “ordinary” operations remains a challenge.
Implementing Quality Control Over Decisions
These 12 questions should be helpful to anyone who relies substantially on
others’ evaluations to make a final decision. But there’s a time and place to
ask them, and there are ways to make them part and parcel of your organization’s
decision-making processes.
When to use the checklist.
This approach is not designed for routine decisions that an executive formally
rubber-stamps. Lisa, the CFO, will want to use it for major capital expenditures
but not her department’s operating budget. The sweet spot for quality control is
decisions that are both important and recurring, and so justify a formal
process. Approving an R&D project, deciding on a large capital expenditure, and
making a midsize acquisition of a company are all examples of “quality
controllable” decisions.
Who should conduct the review.
As we mentioned earlier, the very idea of quality control also assumes a real
separation between the decision maker and the team making the recommendation. In
many instances an executive will overtly or covertly influence a team’s
proposal, perhaps by picking team members whose opinions are already known,
making his or her preferences clear in advance, or signaling opinions during the
recommendation phase. If that is the case, the decision maker becomes a de facto
member of the recommendation team and can no longer judge the quality of the
proposal because his or her own biases have influenced it.
A clear and common sign that this has happened is overlap between the decision
and action stages. If, at the time of a decision, steps have already been taken
to implement it, the executive making the final call has probably communicated a
preference for the outcome being recommended.
Enforcing discipline.
Last, executives need to be prepared to be systematic—something that not all
corporate cultures welcome. As Atul Gawande points out in The Checklist
Manifesto, because each item on a checklist tends to seem sensible and
unsurprising, it is tempting to use checklists partially and selectively.
Doctors who adopted the World Health Organization’s Surgical Safety Checklist
knew that measures as simple as checking the patient’s medication allergies made
sense. But only by going through the checklist completely, systematically, and
routinely did they achieve results—a spectacular reduction in complications and
mortality. Using checklists is a matter of discipline, not genius. Partial
adherence may be a recipe for total failure.
Costs and benefits.
Is applying quality control to decisions a good investment of effort?
Time-pressed executives do not want to delay action, and few corporations are
prepared to devote special resources to a quality control exercise.
But in the end, Bob, Lisa, and Devesh all did, and averted serious problems as a
result. Bob resisted the temptation to implement the price cut his team was
clamoring for at the risk of destroying profitability and triggering a price
war. Instead, he challenged the team to propose an alternative, and eventually
successful, marketing plan. Lisa refused to approve an investment that, as she
discovered, aimed to justify and prop up earlier sunk-cost investments in the
same business. Her team later proposed an investment in a new technology that
would leapfrog the competition. Finally, Devesh signed off on the deal his team
was proposing, but not before additional due diligence had uncovered issues that
led to a significant reduction in the acquisition price.
The real challenge for executives who want to implement decision quality control
is not time or cost. It is the need to build awareness that even highly
experienced, superbly competent, and well intentioned managers are fallible.
Organizations need to realize that a disciplined decision-making process, not
individual genius, is the key to a sound strategy. And they will have to create
a culture of open debate in which such processes can flourish.
About the author
Daniel Kahneman is a senior scholar at the Woodrow Wilson School of Public and
International Affairs at Princeton University, a partner at The Greatest Good, a
consultancy, and a consultant to Guggenheim Partners. He was awarded the Nobel
Prize in Economic Sciences in 2002 for his work (with Amos Tversky) on cognitive
biases.
Dan Lovallo (dan.lovallo@sydney.edu.au) is a professor of business strategy at
the University of Sydney and a senior adviser to McKinsey & Company.
Olivier Sibony (olivier_sibony@mckinsey.com) is a director in the Paris office
of McKinsey & Company.
相关阅读:Cognitive bias
Cognition
Psychology
Taking the bias out of meetings
张律师感谢您的访问。
宪法 法律 行政法规 地方法规 境外法规 司法解释 典型案例 国际法及国际惯例